Put-call parity theory: Difference between revisions
imported>Doug Williamson (Refine wording.) |
imported>Doug Williamson (Add link.) |
||
Line 38: | Line 38: | ||
Therefore market supply and demand pressures will act to quickly re-establish the no arbitrage pricing relationship, following any temporary pricing mis-alignments. | Therefore market supply and demand pressures will act to quickly re-establish the no arbitrage pricing relationship, following any temporary pricing mis-alignments. | ||
Line 47: | Line 45: | ||
* [[Option]] | * [[Option]] | ||
* [[Risk free rate of return]] | * [[Risk free rate of return]] | ||
* [[Interest rate parity]] |
Revision as of 20:43, 28 April 2016
Put-call parity theory links put and call option values via ‘no arbitrage’ market pricing assumptions and the related:
- underlying asset price
- option strike price
- time to maturity and
- theoretically risk-free rate of return.
So for example if the put option value, underlying asset price, strike price, time to maturity, and risk-free rate of return are known, then the call option value can be calculated using the put-call parity relationship:
Underlying asset price + Put value less Call value = Present Value of option strike price
Call value = Underlying asset price + Put value less Present Value of option strike price
In the special case where the strike price of the options is equal to the forward price of the underlying asset, the Put value and the Call value are exactly equal.
Theoretically risk-free portfolios
The no-arbitrage pricing relationship is based on the theory that combinations of market assets and liabilities with the same terminal cash flows, must also have the same present values (i.e. the same theoretical current market prices).
For example both the left side and the right side of the put-call parity formula represent portfolios with the same terminal value:
Underlying asset + Put less Call = Present Value of option strike price
The left side portfolio is built by buying the underlying asset, buying a put option, and selling a call option with the same strike price.
The theoretically risk free terminal value of this portfolio is the equal strike price of the two options.
The present value of this left side portfolio is the present value of the strike price.
The right side portfolio is a deposit of cash.
This cash portfolio also produces a theoretically risk free terminal value, equal to the strike price of the options.
The current market pricing of these two portfolios must in theory be exactly the same.
If this relationship did not hold, there would be an arbitrage opportunity to buy the cheaper portfolio and sell the more expensive one, to earn an immediate risk free profit.
Therefore market supply and demand pressures will act to quickly re-establish the no arbitrage pricing relationship, following any temporary pricing mis-alignments.